Cutting the bias
With the exception of dressmaking, bias is generally undesirable. This is particularly the case when projecting future mortality rates for reserving for pension liabilities. More precisely, a bias towards over-stating mortality rates would be particularly bad because it would lead to under-reserving.
One method for forecasting future mortality is to project changes by cause of death. I have written previously about the numerous technical challenges facing the cause-of-death approach. However, there is also a fundamental academic objection to this approach: it is biased. This is covered by a number of researchers, two of whom we quote below:
Mortality projections disaggregated by cause of death have been found in practice to be more pessimistic than those without disaggregation [...]. The reason is straightforward: over time the overall trend becomes dominated by the trend for those causes with the slowest decline.
Wong-Fupuy and Haberman (2004) Projecting mortality trends, NAAJ.
When Wong-Fupuy and Haberman write "pessimistic", they mean the over-estimation of mortality rates. This is exactly the kind of bias you do not want when you are worried about the adequacy of pension-fund reserves. If a company uses cause-of-death projections as a basis for reserving, auditors and regulators will want to know how the in-built tendency for bias has been overcome.
Add new comment